Pages

A Perspective on the Coase "Theorem"

"'Coase's Theorem' says that once we determine who can legally do what, externalities will vanish as actors pay one another off. This methodology - either the victims bribe the perpetrator to stop the distasteful behavior (when the perpetrator has the legal right to do it) or the perpetrator bribes the victim to put up with the distasteful outcome (when the victims have a right not to suffer the pain) - is considered an epochal innovation in American economics and jurisprudence. Even without understanding all the details and context, this tells us a great deal about our intellectual culture since, in fact, Coase's methodology doesn't work.
  1. Bargains made with only two parties, perpetrator and victim, will rarely if ever be efficient.
  2. Whenever the perpetrator is a corporation and the victim a far-flung collection of disparate individuals, the latter is at such a disadvantage in seeking recompense that without intervention correction rarely takes place at all.
  3. Coase's methodology provides a 'bully incentive' for anyone able to muster the courts on their behalf. Suppose Z owns a train. If we have the legal right to spew sparks, we should create the most spark-spewing train we can. If we have the right to be noisy, we should create a decibel demon. Whenever anyone with the means to pursue legal claims has a right that could cause others pain, they should threaten to exercise it and then extort bribery payments to desist. In the absence of a specific legal prohibition, a bully walking down the street should spit on everyone, claiming that he will only suffer the pains of stopping if his vitims bribe him to do so.
Not surprisingly, Coase's 'extort the victim,' 'empower the powerful' analysis was welcome as soon as economists could understand its utility to elites able to make legal claims here, there, and everywhere, thereby profitably spitting this way and that with impunity.

Why the hoopla for Coase? First, Coase's Theorem, better named the Bully Theorem, reinstates markets and privatization as optimal, even providing an argument against unwanted government regulation. Second, it elevates 'property rights' to the defining position in jurisprudence and establishes a logic for dealing with externalities perfectly suited to co-optation by capital." -- Michael Albert (November 1991)

0 comments:

Post a Comment

  • Stiglitz the Keynesian... Web review of economics: Stigliz has an article, "Capitalist Fools", in the January issue of Vanity Fair. He argues that the new depression is the result of:Firing...
  • It's Never Enough Until Your He... Web review of economics: Aaron Swartz quotes a paper by Louis Pascal posing a thought experiment. I wonder if many find this argument emotionally unsatisfying. It...
  • Michele Boldrin Confused About Marx... Web review of economics: Michele Boldrin has written a paper in which supposedly Marxian themes are treated in a Dynamic Stochastic Equilibrium Model (DSGE). He...
  • Negative Price Wicksell Effect, Pos... Web review of economics: 1.0 IntroductionI have previously suggested a taxonomy of Wicksell effects. This post presents an example with:The cost-minimizing...
  • Designing A Keynesian Stimulus Plan... Web review of economics: Some version of this New York Times article contains the following passage:"A blueprint for such spending can be found in a study financed...
  • Robert Paul Wolff Blogging On Books... Web review of economics: Here Wolff provides an overview of Marx, agrees with Morishima that Marx was a great economist, and mentions books by the analytical...
  • Simple and Expanded Reproduction... Web review of economics: 1.0 IntroductionThis post presents a model in which a capitalist economy smoothly reproduces itself. The purpose of such a model is not to...
  • How Individuals Can Choose, Even Th... Web review of economics: 1.0 IntroductionI think of this post as posing a research question. S. Abu Turab Rizvi re-interprets the primitives of social choice theory...